wp_13_04
wp_13_04
wp_13_04
Analyzing public decisions using benefit-cost is anathema for some, a truth nostrum for others
and a targeted diagnostic for a few (heavily concentrated among economists). Its surface
simplicity and its subtle complexities make it easy to lie, accidentally or not. Conversely,
discerning what truth there may be about public policy is aided by warning signs of lying and
advocated for use on a broader basis primarily by Republicans. It’s used by charities such as the
Robin Hood Foundation in New York to help allocate charitable giving and by the World Bank
to inform the international allocation of funding. Governments issue guidelines on its use and
textbooks struggle to explain how to do it right but don’t provide the vivid examples of doing it
wrong that are so hard to forget. Most of us end up hearing fragments of studies as sound bites
about how good or bad the “bottom line” is for some program. What is benefit-cost analysis
Benefit-cost analysis tries to answer whether a society is better off by taking an action when
impacts of all kinds are considered, including those outside the marketplace. Dollar values (in
the U.S.) are used to weight the impacts such as reduced building damages or deaths and these
impacts are added up “to whomsoever they accrue”. The bottom line measure, the eponymous
benefits less the costs (net benefit) is defined as a measure of economic efficiency (and who can
be against efficiency?). A positive value is standardly interpreted to mean that society will be
1
better off by taking the action (the subtler complexity is in Lie #4 below). This apparent
simplicity obscures numerous challenges in practice and interpretation so in this political season
I offer the following lies and how to avoid them as aids to distinguish among good, bad and ugly
analyses.
Start easy with this no-brainer tactic: Include impacts that slant the benefit or cost your way and
dispute or ignore those that tilt the other way. If you want to reduce the benefits of regulations to
reduce oil spills, exclude those who would pay a small bit more to avoid such events even if they
never visit the Gulf or Alaska (officially, non-use value). If a rule about the cleanliness of
drinking water also affects how much to clean up old industrial sites and you want to reduce
How not to lie: Include all the impacts and values for which credible (ah, there’s the rub)
estimates exist and which seem potentially large enough to change an opinion. No one is
prescient enough nor are there enough data to include everything, but see that the core elements
What you can do. Ask yourself “Are there major elements missing, or too many present in this
analysis?” This is perhaps the most challenging detective work, can you find the impact that
didn’t bark in the night and didn’t make it into the report?
Choose a comparison that makes your desired impacts larger and your costs smaller, perhaps
even by choosing different baselines for benefits and costs. Impacts only exist if there is a
2
change from some starting point, the baseline. You see this when political Party A touts its
impact starting from a low point of the business cycle and political Party B responds measuring
from the high point of the cycle (or vice versa). Or build an inflation factor into costs but not
benefits (or vice versa). Or ignore history that States or industry or technology seem to be
moving over time and assume all factors will stay constant if that helps you.
How not to lie: Be consistent and clear about the baseline, including whether factors are
changing over time. The standard baseline is in comparison to doing nothing (the status quo) but
economies evolve in complex ways so a baseline that evolves over time is ok.
What you can do: Ask yourself “What is the basis of comparison? Is that reasonable and is it the
After you compute the benefits of the policy (typically by looking at benefits received by all of
consumers, industry, and changes in government revenue), also count the number of employees
and the amount they will be paid as a benefit. After all, labor is about two-thirds of all costs in
the US and so if you can count two-thirds of the cost as a benefit, then that gets you a long ways
toward a positive net benefit. A variation on this is to count as a benefit the new jobs in your
local region while ignoring the loss or shift in jobs from another region. This is politically
How not to lie: Decide whether unemployment rates are normal or high. If they are normal,
then there is no additional benefit from new jobs as your new job is just taking labor effort away
from some other job, it washes out. Recent times have seen unusually high rates of
unemployment which does create a justification for a partial benefit from new employment. It’s
3
partial because it depends on the wage a person requires to work. If a person would work for
next to nothing, then the whole wage is a benefit; if they won’t work for anything less than a
multiple of the minimum wage, then the benefit is the wage less the amount for which they will
choose to work. A back of the envelope approach on who will work for how much suggests
What you can do: Ask yourself, “Will this policy be implemented during full employment or
high unemployment?” and “Are the new jobs just being taken away from another location that is
Lie #4: Cite the bottom line as a crystal clear measure of improvement.
Find a report with a positive net value for the project or policy and tout it as quantitative support
that it is better for all. Corollary, find a negative value and state it’s bad for society. Don’t
mention caveats, they are such tiresome things and time is short.
How not lie: Be cautious about your conclusion. A positive value is like a green light on a
larger set of dashboard instruments. Society will unambiguously be better off only if
compensation is paid to all who incur costs which bears its own problems; or if the value of an
additional dollar is the same to all people, whether rich or poor, and society values equally a
dollar going to any individual. Falling off this unlikely knife edge leaves ambiguous the bottom
line of a single benefit-cost analysis. Treating everyone equally is a reasonable place to start and
the professional standard but it is not always the end of the story.
What you can do: Ask yourself, “Am I comfortable with adding up everyone’s impacts no
matter who they are on this issue?” “Is there evidence on who is impacted that is re-incorporated
4
Lie #5: Act as if a number is certain
Be confident, be very very confident. Report impacts in small fractions, report dollar values to
some small amount; hundreds or tens of dollars, or heh, go all the way and report the total in
cents. Don’t worry about conveying uncertainty about the number and don’t get bogged down in
How not to lie: Convey some measure of the accuracy of your measurements. Ideally this is
reflected in the number of significant digits (no, that’s not how many nails and toes have polish)
such as whether your data are precise only to the millions or by reporting statistical measures of
dispersion such as a standard error. Carry out “what if” or sensitivity analysis or in today’s easy
to computer world, do a “Monte Carlo” simulation which is like doing hundreds or thousands of
What you can do. Ask “Does there seem to be a false level of precision in this analysis?” and
“Are we told whether the results change if reasonable changes are made to the analysis?”
Provide the number, any way you can, that you think your boss or your client is expecting;
sometimes paraphrased as “I can get you any number you want, what do you want it to be?”
How not to lie: Even if there is no Hippocratic Oath for economists or policy analysts, there ar e
professionally acceptable ways of doing things, some gray areas, and some that are wrong. Do
not deviate dramatically from standard practice. If you choose to deviate substantially, take
more time to explain and get your method reviewed or even published. Besides, it is
5
professionally embarrassing when it’s revealed you caved to your boss; your reputation is a
repeat game.
You get the drift. Below is an abbreviated list of additional ways to lie and how to avoid lying.
1. Slant the question Neutrally identify the problem and its causation
This is all about greed; or jobs.
2. Assess only one alternative Assess reasonable alternatives including different
Rebuild the New Orleans levee to the sizes, different approaches, and doing nothing
height it was before
3. Ignore time “Discount” future values (the challenge is the
Just add up the new government appropriate rate).
revenue from gambling for the next 20
years.
4. Be vague about whose benefits and Clearly define who has standing (whose benefits
costs count and costs count). All citizens? Only those in a
Assess the impact of military base region?
closures only on the local region or be
unclear if the benefits of thievery accrue
to the thief.
5. Omit a summary table with Include a limited number of summary tables,
performance measures perhaps one for impacts in their natural units (e.g.
Make it hard to integrate the analysis, injuries, crimes), and one for the monetized
as with an analysis of the cost of values in each category.
sprinklers in nursing homes in which
benefits and costs were kept in different
units and distinct from each other.
6. Use misleading graphics or statistics See How to Lie with Statistics by Darrell Huff
For instance, truncate the vertical axis
so that what looks like a large change is
a small change compared to the total.
7. Ignore relevant differences among Take into account policy relevant differences such
people as those potentially associated with income,
In the benefits of emergency planning gender, age…
(or the cost of a disaster), assume an
average of 1.8 cars per household no
matter their income so that everyone
can drive out of harm’s way.
8. Ignore qualitative elements (not Qualitatively describe elements which cannot be
quantified or not monetized) quantified and put into monetary values.
Measure the cost of rape as hospital
and police reporting costs.
6
HOW TO LIE HOW NOT TO LIE
Of course, lying is a creative art and the salient methods listed above have infinite variation. No
group has a monopoly on the art; in my experience non-governmental organizations are as likely
as industry or government to shade the truth. At the same time, there are dedicated people in
each type of organization who are concerned about truth-telling both within their organization