HDL 2196
HDL 2196
HDL 2196
PERMISSIONS
http://journals.cambridge.org/action/displaySpecialPage?pageId=4676
Institutional repositories
2.4. The author may post the VoR version of the article (in PDF or HTML form) in the Institutional
Repository of the institution in which the author worked at the time the article was first submitted, or
(for appropriate journals) in PubMed Central or UK PubMed Central or arXiv, no sooner than one
year after first publication of the article in the Journal, subject to file availability and provided the
posting includes a prominent statement of the full bibliographical details, a copyright notice in the
name of the copyright holder (Cambridge University Press or the sponsoring Society, as appropriate),
and a link to the online edition of the Journal at Cambridge Journals Online.
23 April 2014
http://hdl.handle.net/2440/2196
State-Directed Diffusion of Technology:
The Mechanization of Cotton Harvesting
in Soviet Central Asia
RICHARD POMFRET
When Soviet central planners began to mechanize the cotton harvest in earnest in
1958, they expected more rapid diffusion than the market-driven process that had
begun in the United States a decade earlier. But despite high output of cotton-picking
machines, the share of the crop harvested mechanically grew more slowly than in the
United States. The factor proportions in Central Asia did not justify mechanization:
although planners could enforce introduction of the new technology, investment in
cotton-harvesting machines was largely a waste of resources. The costs of premature
introduction are estimated at over $1 billion in 1960s prices.
The Journal of Economic History, Vol. 62, No. 1 (March 2002). © The Economic History
Association. All rights reserved. ISSN 0022-0507.
Address correspondence to Richard Pomfret, School of Economics, Adelaide University, Adelaide
SA 5005, Australia. E-mail: richard.pomfret@adelaide.edu.au.
Most of the research behind this article was done during a sabbatical leave spent at the University
of California, San Diego, and I am grateful to the Graduate School of International Relations and
Pacific Studies for hospitality. Helpful comments on earlier drafts were provided by Michelle Barnes,
Alan Olmstead, Jonathan Pincus, John Siegfried, the editor of this JOURNAL and three anonymous
referees.
1
On the importance of technical improvements (the D in R&D) and of informational gaps and
interdependencies, see Rosenberg, Inside the Black Box. The classic account of the S-shaped diffusion
path of new technology is Griliches, “Hybrid Corn.” The threshold model introduces indivisibilities,
and combined with the size distribution of potential adopters generates an S-shaped diffusion path; for
application to the diffusion of mechanical reapers, see David, “Mechanization”; and Pomfret, “Mecha-
nization.” On tractor adoption, see Ankli, “Horses”; and Lew, “Diffusion.” The threshold model has
been criticized by Olmstead, “Mechanization” and “Diffusion”; and by Olmstead and Rohde, “Beyond
the Threshold,” who also emphasize the uncertainty inherent in the market and the nature of credit
institutions and farm organization. On the diffusion of tractors among U.S. cotton farmers see Musoke,
“Mechanizing”; and Whatley, “History.”
170
State-Directed Diffusion 171
2
See Musoke and Olmstead, “Rise”; and Grove, “Farmers.”
3
Whatley, “New Estimates,” p. 199.
4
Priority was given to replacement of back-breaking work by modern machines in part because it
provided good publicity when, at the peak of Soviet prestige in the Third World, Soviet Central Asia
was held up as a model, contrasted to southern neighbors both in the satisfaction of basic needs and in
economic dynamism. Western economists also accepted this image; see Nove and Newth, Soviet
Middle East; Conolly, Beyond the Urals, pp. 55–241; and Wilber, Soviet Model.
5
The U.S. data are from Musoke and Olmstead, “Rise,” pp. 405–06. The minor Soviet exception was
Kazakhstan, where the reported share of the harvest picked by machine exceeded 75 percent in 1985
and 1988, although these spikes look implausible in the long-term context (Table 6). Less than 5
percent of Soviet land under cotton in the late 1980s was in Kazakhstan (Table 2).
172 Pomfret
100
90
United States
USSR
80
70
Percent of harvest mechanized
60
50
40
30
20
10
0
1949 1954 1959 1964 1969 1974 1979 1984 1989
FIGURE 1
THE MECHANIZATION OF COTTON-HARVESTING IN THE UNITED STATES AND THE
USSR, 1949–1988
Asian peasants on the land and prevent the social disruption associated with
rural–urban migration. On these views, it is not the state-directed approach
itself that was at fault, but rather poor implementation by planners. I, how-
ever, shall argue that the “failure” of mechanization was due to resistance
by cotton growers. The central authorities were pushing for too-rapid diffu-
sion, and by the 1980s they failed to maintain even the diffusion levels
achieved in the 1960s and 1970s due to resistance at the level of the kolkhoz
(collective farm). Planners saw the benefits of mechanization as self-evident,
ignoring its real and opportunity costs, as well as its distributional impact.
How do we know that the intended diffusion was premature? One indica-
tion is the phenomenon of idle machinery during the Soviet period. Even
when machines were available, kolkhoz managers chose to leave them idle
and have the cotton picked by hand. Despite the low valuation by the users,
real resources went into the manufacture of the machines. Another sign that
diffusion had been too rapid is that when the post-Soviet successor states
shifted to greater market orientation in the 1990s, demechanization contin-
ued apace.6 Although reliable data on the share of machine-picked cotton in
6
Of course, many things changed after the collapse of central planning which may have affected the
demand for machinery, but the fundamental factor proportions had not. Characterizing the successor
State-Directed Diffusion 173
post-Soviet Central Asia are hard to come by, anecdotal evidence suggests
that hand-picking became even more prevalent in the 1990s.7 By the turn of
this century, machine production had collapsed.
I will first set the scene by providing technical background material and
discussing the role of political leaders and central planners at the innovation
stage, where some of the Soviet Union’s latecomer advantage was dissipated
by political intervention. A following section discusses arguments that neo-
colonial political leaders hampered the diffusion process. I go on to posit an
alternative hypothesis, that resistance to mechanization was at the kolkhoz
level where, for the majority of adult male members, the costs of mechaniza-
tion exceeded the benefits; I assess the outcome in terms of social costs and
benefits, and argue that although the interests of kolkhoz managers were
determined within the framework of collectivized agriculture, their actions
reflected the economic unsuitability of mechanical harvesting in labor-abun-
dant Soviet Central Asia. A lower-bound valuation of the resources wasted
in premature diffusion is $1 billion at 1960 prices. The final section draws
some conclusions, emphasizing that while public intervention can accelerate
the pace of technological diffusion, this may not be a desirable outcome.
economies as more market-oriented is not to deny that the cotton sector remains highly distorted in the
successor states, most strikingly with state monopsonies in Uzbekistan and Turkmenistan. Neverthe-
less, the end of central planning did lead to changes. Especially significant in the present context is the
disconnection of the machinery industry from the cotton growers, who are now less pressured to accept
delivery of new machines. In the planned economy, the level of compulsion in the labor market may
have reduced the incentive to economize on labor, but the shift to market-based labor allocation should
have reversed this bias. Note that in analyzing factor proportions input markets are of greater signifi-
cance than the lack of competition in the output market, assuming that decision-makers place some
weight on cost reduction.
7
The World Bank’s poverty assessment of Tajikistan (20285-TJ, 29 June 2000, p. 64) mentions that
“cotton harvesting is almost exclusively manual.” Andrew Apostolou, an Oxford University historian,
refers to the Uzbekistan 1999 cotton crop, “an incredible 96.5 percent of which was collected by hand”
(“Uzbek Model”).
8
The quotation is from Hon, “Rust,” p. 384. Strippers, which snapped cotton bolls off at the top of
the stalk and failed to distinguish ripe bolls from unripe ones and trash, were used in Texas and
Oklahoma after 1926, but were less efficient than the later cotton pickers which picked only ripened
bolls. Production of cotton pickers appears to have begun in 1946, when 107 machines were produced;
by 1951, over 3,500 machines were being produced annually in the United States (Street, New Revolu-
tion, p. 133).
174 Pomfret
Total
TABLE 2
COTTON SOWN IN SOVIET CENTRAL ASIA, 1940–1988
(thousands of hectares)
Republic 1940 1950 1960 1965 1970 1980 1985 1988
12
Hodnett, “Technology,” p. 77 (italics in original).
13
The ability to make such economic experiments is identified as a key advantage of capitalism over
socialism by Rosenberg, Exploring the Black Box, pp. 87–108.
14
Khrushchev’s experience of agriculture was based on grain-farming regions of Ukraine and
Russia. He had little sympathy for Central Asian farmers, whom he considered to be lazy and shiftless.
Procurement prices for cotton were held back after 1954 because he considered them already too high
relative to grain prices. After 1954 Khrushchev’s main goal in Central Asia was promotion of the
Virgin Lands scheme to increase grain output in northern Kazakhstan; disruption of cotton-machinery
production could free resources to produce tractors and grain harvesters. When cotton output failed to
meet targets, he blamed the political leaders, and purged the leadership of every cotton-growing
republic between December 1958 and May 1961. By contrast, under Brezhnev the political leadership
was remarkably stable in Central Asia.
15
Hodnett, “Technology,” p. 78.
State-Directed Diffusion 177
TABLE 3
ANNUAL OUTPUT OF COTTON HARVESTING MACHINES IN THE USSR, 1950–1979
(thousands)
Year No. Year No. Year No.
Gregory Gleason has provided the most sustained analysis of the slow
mechanization of the Central Asian cotton harvest. He focuses on the labor-
market effects of mechanization, arguing that it would have displaced the
native population from the land and created a potential source of unrest in
the towns of the region, or in other parts of the Soviet Union as they relo-
cated in search of work. Moreover, the urbanization of Central Asia’s work-
force would be associated with inflows of skilled labor from elsewhere in
the Soviet Union. Neither politicians in Moscow nor the leadership in the
Central Asian republics welcomed these consequences, and in the Brezhnev
era they conspired to discourage mechanization in order to forestall its social
consequences.16 Gleason concludes that “Moscow officials failed to order
the agricultural machinery industry to produce that which was required for
full mechanization,” and he predicted this would change with perestroika,
when market forces would push kolkhoz managers to mechanize in order to
cut costs and be competitive.
The idea that cotton kolkhozy were starved of machinery is belied by the
production record. The stock of machines continued to increase into the
1980s,17 even after the share of cotton harvested by machine had begun to
16
Gleason sees evidence of this complicity in the longevity of Central Asian leaders between 1961
and 1982, when there was only one change in the top official of the five republics. He also sees local
kolkhoz managers condoning the anti-mechanization strategy, because their influence was related to
the number of workers on the collective. See Gleason, “Marketization”; the quotation in the next
sentence is from p. 80.
17
See Table 4.
178 Pomfret
with hand-picking was between 2.5 and 5 percent, rising over time as the average age of pickers
increased.
27
The difference was about 10 percent in 1963 (Hodnett, “Technology,” p. 115 n93).
28
On the United States, see Street, New Revolution, p. 170; and Whatley, “New Estimates,” p. 201.
In 1999 in Uzbekistan cotton-harvester drivers were paid 100–200 sums per ton picked, whereas hand
pickers were paid 8–9 sums per kilogram, so that the reduction in labor costs from mechanization was
at least 97.5 percent.
29
Annual use of cotton-harvesting machines in the United States in the 1950s and 1960s varied from
225 hours in the southeast, to 350 hours in the Mississippi Delta, to 500 in the west; see Whatley, “New
Estimates,” p. 215. The main reason for this discrepancy was the drier and more reliable climate in the
west compared to the mud and morning mist of the southeast coastal regions. Musoke and Olmstead
(“Rise”) emphasize larger farm size and climate as reasons why Californian cotton farms were best-
suited to mechanical harvesting in the United States. Similar features in the core cotton-growing areas
of Central Asia suggest that neither physical conditions nor kolkhoz fragmentation are plausible expla-
nations for the slow diffusion of machine-picking.
State-Directed Diffusion 181
30
Dienes (Soviet Asia, p. 131) reviews some of this literature, concluding that in 1979 surplus labor
was about 1.1 million in the Kyrgyz, Tajik, Turkmen, and Uzbek republics combined, and around
315,000 in the Kazakh republic. Marnie (“Soviet Labor Market,” pp. 203–05) estimates that in 1984
over a million people were voluntarily or involuntarily unemployed in the Uzbek republic, the core of
the Soviet cotton economy, and the non-employed amounted to 14 percent of the working-age popula-
tion, compared to 5.5 percent in the Russian republic. Klugman (“Wages,” p. 34), however, points to
large regional variations in Uzbekistan between cotton-growing areas, such as the labor-scarce Dzijak
region, and the surplus-labor Ferghana Valley.
31
In 1986 and 1987, 650,000 to 700,000 schoolchildren, 140,000 college and vocational school
students, and an unreported number of urban workers harvested cotton in the Uzbek republic (Craumer,
“Agricultural Change,” p. 162). In the Tajik republic over 300,000 students and industrial workers were
drafted during harvest seasons in the mid-1980s for one-and-a-half to two months cotton picking
(Dienes, Soviet Asia, p. 130).
32
Hodnett, “Technology,” pp. 85–86; and Lubin, Labor and Nationality, pp. 181–82 and 188.
33
Marnie, “Soviet Labor Market,” p. 223. This progressivity was more pronounced in the Tajik
republic, rising from 16 percent to 45 percent. In the Kyrgyz and Turkmen republics, the share fell as
family income rose. The share of family income coming from private plots was much lower in the
Turkmen republic (8–16 percent) than in the other three republics covered by Marnie.
182 Pomfret
machines themselves essentially free. One reason might be that their objec-
tives focused on meeting output targets, so that wastage costs, while rela-
tively minor to a firm in a market economy, loomed large in the Soviet
context; mechanization would in effect require planting more hectares with
cotton. Also, managers’ loyalty to their male colleagues would have discour-
aged disruption of the private-plot system, and led to little weight being
placed on the arduous labor done by others. In the specific institutional con-
text of Soviet Central Asia, central planners and kolkhoz managers were
acting at cross-purposes with respect to mechanization, and the question
arises of whether the resistance to mechanization was desirable on any
grounds other than the local decision-makers’ self-interest within the Soviet
system.
COST–BENEFIT ANALYSIS
over five cents per pound.37 Australia, the other high-wage cotton-growing
country, also mechanized harvesting. Major producers such as India, China,
and Pakistan, however, continue to harvest by hand because their labor costs
do not justify mechanization.38 Soviet Central Asia was between these ex-
tremes of labor costs, and closer to Egypt or Iran or Turkey, none of which
has mechanized the cotton harvest.
One cannot, of course, rule out externalities. The social disruption of
mechanization would have been considerable,39 but not necessarily negative
and, as emphasized above, there is little evidence of policymakers delaying
mechanization for this reason. More plausibly, Soviet planners may have
placed great weight on the propaganda benefits of modernization. An eco-
nomic price was, however, paid for any such psychic benefits.
How high was this price? The phenomenon of idle machines suggests that
their true economic value was close to zero, and this is supported by the
collapse of sales after 1991. In that case the cost of premature mechanization
was the resource cost of building the machines. Over 60,000 machines were
produced in the 1960s (Table 3) and, although I have no data on deprecia-
tion rates, the numbers in Table 4 suggest that this flow was perhaps main-
tained through the 1970s and declined in the 1980s, before collapsing to a
few hundred per year in the late 1990s (Table 5).40 Soviet prices tell us little
about the resources going into each machine, because input prices, transport
costs, and output prices for producer goods were all meaningless in the
centrally planned economy. During the 1960s the list prices for generic
standard-model cotton pickers in the United States ranged from $6,000 to
$10,000.41 Given the competitive nature of the U.S. industry, this could be
considered the “world price” of a standard machine and, if Soviet machines
were of the same quality, then it provides a shadow price. Thus, during the
1960s the opportunity cost of premature mechanization of cotton-picking
was in the range of $360–600 million. The amount may have been slightly
37
Labor costs included not just the minimum wage payments of about $3.50 per hundredweight, but
also recruitment and organizing costs (0.86 and 1.16 cents per pound); see Whatley, “New Estimates,”
p. 211.
38
In 1999 the countries with the largest cotton production were China, the United States, India,
Pakistan, Uzbekistan, Turkey, Australia, Brazil, Turkmenistan, and Greece (Table 1).
39
In the southern United States the mechanization of cotton and subsequent release of unskilled labor
was arguably the greatest single economic and social event of the twentieth century, transforming not
only the cotton sector but also the entire labor market and social structure, leading to large-scale
migration to the northern United States and reinforcing demands for civil rights.
40
In interviews at the Tashkent Institute of Engineers for Irrigation and Agricultural Mechanization
(TIEIAM) in 1997 I was told that 2,000 cotton-picking machines were produced per year in the 1980s.
Output dropped to very low levels in the early 1990s, although TIEIAM staff explained that this was
due to input supply disruptions (especially steel) and technical problems which were being resolved
by negotiating a joint venture with a U.S. producer. With a total academic staff of 422, and 514 stu-
dents registered in its Faculty of Agricultural Mechanization, TIEIAM clearly maintains the tradition
of central advocacy of mechanization.
41
Whatley, “New Estimates,” p. 209.
184 Pomfret
TABLE 4
STOCK OF COTTON-HARVESTING MACHINES, 1960–1986
(thousands)
Republic 1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1986
less in the next two decades, but it is unlikely that the total (undiscounted)
cost at 1960s prices was less than $1 billion.42
CONCLUSIONS
Labor productivity in Soviet Central Asia was very low. Cotton output per
day of labor in 1953 was even lower in the Soviet Union than in Egypt.43
Labor productivity increased during the 1950s and 1960s, but it fell in all the
cotton-growing republics between 1970 and 1987.44 Despite the large expen-
diture on irrigation, machinery, and fertilizers, the returns to both land and
labor used in cotton production were diminishing in the final two decades
of the Soviet Union, and the cotton economy was imposing huge environ-
mental costs as chemical fertilizers drained into the rivers and irrigation
projects cut off the flow of water to the Aral Sea.45 Soviet planners recog-
nized the low level of labor productivity and saw the need for mechaniza-
tion, but low opportunity cost of labor is a reason for doubting the appropri-
ateness of labor-saving investment.
Politicization and central planning delayed the development of the cotton-
harvester industry in the 1950s; once it did take off, the system’s rigidity and
biases restricted the development of technical improvements and of repair
facilities. These are, however, minor features of the story of the anemic
42
Because some machines had positive value in relatively labor-scarce areas such as Dzijak this
could be an overestimate, but in other respects it is a minimum estimate. The U.S. prices are for
bottom-of-the-line one-row pickers, whereas Soviet output included two-row pickers (which were
twice as expensive as one-row pickers in the United States) and other non-standard models. As noted
in Table 3, data on machine production in the 1950s and 1960s are imprecise about quality. Moreover,
substantial costs were incurred in the design and retooling associated with the SkhM-48 and subsequent
shift to horizontal-spindle machines.
43
Economic Commission for Europe, “Regional Policy,” p. 60; and Hodnett, “Technology,” p. 73.
44
Craumer, “Agricultural Change,” p. 159.
45
In March 1989 Gorbachev was reported in Pravda as complaining that over the previous 20 years
in Uzbekistan 1.6 million new hectares of irrigated land had been created and productive forces in
agriculture had increased sixfold, but gross production was up only 78 percent; see Gleason, “Marketi-
zation,” p. 72.
State-Directed Diffusion 185
TABLE 5
ANNUAL OUTPUT OF COTTON-HARVESTING MACHINES IN UZBEKISTAN, 1994–1999
Year No.
1994 651
1995 1,121
1996 863
1997 1,049
1998 351
1999 278
Note: So far as I am aware, no cotton harvesters were produced elsewhere in the former USSR; so these
figures are comparable with Table 3.
Source: Ministry of Macroeconomics and Statistics data reported in Uzbek Economic Trends,
January–March 2000, p. 104.
46
Irrigation projects, the other huge capital investment in Central Asian agriculture, also failed to
distinguish between kolkhoz-level incentives and social welfare, but in this case kolkhozy and central
planners tended to be on the same side. Irrigation projects were generally supported by kolkhoz mem-
bers, who saw private benefits from free or heavily subsidized water, which helped them to achieve
cotton-output targets as well as improving their private plots, with little cost to them. Little attention
was paid to effective use of the water, a scarce resource in the Central Asian desert, or to the environ-
mental costs of existing and planned irrigation projects. Even as late as the mid-1980s official opinion
was still in denial as to the costs of desiccation of the Aral Sea, and Chernenko was still considering
diversion of Siberian rivers. The common feature was the grand commitment to modernization without
attention to complexities “on the ground.”
47
Gleason, “Marketization.”
186 Pomfret
TABLE 6
PERCENTAGE OF COTTON HARVESTED BY MACHINE IN THE MAIN COTTON-
PRODUCING SOVIET REPUBLICS, 1965–1988
Uzbek Turkmen Tajik Kazakh Kyrgyz
1965 23 ? 14 21 33
1970 33 32 22 41 39
1975 46 47 28 69 62
1980 63 52 36 63 51
1981 68 49 29 51 61
1982 54 41 22 45 63
1983 34 43 12 43 49
1984 31 26 11 39 60
1985 40 52 13 76 23
1986 42 47 22 ? 69
1987 45 ? 20 57 69
1988 47 65 24 78 ?
Note: The USSR points in Figure 1 are weighted by republican production levels, from Table 1.
Hodnett (“Technology,” p. 79) gives similar figures: at “the end of the 1960s” 33 percent of the entire
Soviet crop was machine-harvested, with variation across republics: Kyrgyz 39 percent (1970);
Turkmen 33 percent (1970); Tajik 21 percent (1969); Azeri 9 percent (1965); and Uzbek 1.7 percent
(1955), 2 percent (1958), 11 percent (1962), 24 percent (1965), 29 percent (1969), and 34 percent
(1970).
Source: Craumer, “Agricultural Change,” p. 161.
REFERENCES
Ankli, Robert. “Horses vs. Tractors on the Corn Belt.” Agricultural History 54, (January
1980): 134–48.
Apostolou, Andrew. “The Uzbek Model confronts a Crisis.” Eurasianet, posted 5 October
2000 at http://www.eurasianet.org.
Conolly, Violet. Beyond the Urals: Economic Developments in Soviet Asia. London: Ox-
ford University Press, 1967.
Craumer, Peter. “Agricultural Change, Labor Supply, and Rural Out-Migration in Soviet
Central Asia.” In Geographic Perspectives on Soviet Central Asia, edited by Robert
Lewis, 132–80. London: Routledge, 1992.
David, Paul. “The Mechanization of Reaping in the Ante-Bellum Midwest.” In Industrial-
ization in Two Systems: Essays in Honor of Alexander Gerschenkron, edited by Henry
Rosovsky, 3–39. New York: John Wiley, 1966.
Dienes, Leslie. Soviet Asia: Economic Development and National Policy Choices. Boulder:
Westview Press, 1987.
Economic Commission for Europe. “Regional Economic Policy in the Soviet Union: The
Case of Central Asia.” Economic Bulletin for Europe 9, no. 3 (1957): 49–75.
Feldman, Elliott. Concorde and Dissent. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1985.
Gleason, Gregory. “Between Moscow and Tashkent: The Politics of the Uzbek Cotton
Complex.” Ph.D. dissertation, University of California, Davis, 1984.
______. “Marketization and Migration: The Politics of Cotton in Central Asia.” Journal of
Soviet Nationalities 1 (Summer 1990): 66–98.
Griliches, Zvi. “Hybrid Corn: An Exploration in the Economics of Technological Change.”
Econometrica 25 (October 1957): 501–22.
Grove, Wayne. “Farmers at the Technological Crossroads: Post-WWII Diffusion of the
Mechanical Cotton Harvester.” Unpublished paper, January 1997 (drawn from a PhD
dissertation at the University of Illinois).
188 Pomfret
Hodnett, Grey. “Technology and Social Change in Soviet Central Asia: The Politics of
Cotton Growing.” In Soviet Politics and Society in the 1970s, edited by Henry W.
Morton and Rudolf L. Tokes, 60–117. New York: Free Press, 1974.
Hon, Ralph. “The Rust Cotton Picker.” Southern Economic Journal 3 (April 1937):
381–92.
Khan, Azizur Rahman, and Dharam Ghai. Collective Agriculture and Rural Development
in Soviet Central Asia. Basingstoke: Macmillan, 1979.
Klugman, Jeni. “Wages in Transition: The Case of Uzbekistan.” Ph.D. Thesis, Australian
National University, 1998.
Lew, Byron. “The Diffusion of Tractors on the Canadian Prairies: The Threshold Model
and the Problem of Uncertainty.” Explorations in Economic History 37 (April 2000):
189–216.
Lubin, Nancy. Labor and Nationality in Soviet Central Asia: An Uneasy Compromise.
Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1984.
Marnie, Sheila. “The Soviet Labor Market in Transition.” Ph.D. Thesis. European Univer-
sity Institute, Badia Fiesolana, Italy, 1992.
Musoke, Moses. “Mechanizing Cotton Production in the American South: The Tractor,
1915–1960.” Explorations in Economic History 18 (October 1981): 347–75.
Musoke, Moses, and Alan Olmstead. “The Rise of the Cotton Industry in California: A
Comparative Perspective.” This JOURNAL 42 (June 1982): 385–412.
Nove, Alec, and J. A. Newth. The Soviet Middle East: A Communist Model for Develop-
ment. London: Allen & Unwin, 1966.
Olmstead, Alan. “The Mechanization of Reaping and Mowing.” This JOURNAL 35 (June
1975): 327–52.
______. “The Diffusion of the Reaper: One More Time!” This JOURNAL 39 (June 1979):
475–76.
Olmstead, Alan, and Paul Rohde. “Beyond the Threshold: An Analysis of the Characteris-
tics and Behavior of Early Reaper Adopters.” This JOURNAL 55 (March 1995): 27–57.
Pomfret, Richard. “The Mechanization of Reaping in Nineteenth Century Ontario: A Case
Study of the Diffusion of Embodied Technical Change.” This JOURNAL 36 (June
1976): 399–415.
______. “Agrarian Reform in Uzbekistan: Why has the Chinese Model Failed to Deliver?”
Economic Development and Cultural Change 48 (January 2000): 269–84.
Rosenberg, Nathan. Inside the Black Box. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1982.
______. Exploring the Black Box. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1994.
Street, James. The New Revolution in the Cotton Economy: Mechanization and its Conse-
quences. Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press, 1957.
Sutton, Antony. Western Technology and Soviet Economic Development, 1930 to 1945.
Stanford, CA: Hoover Institution, 1971.
Whatley, Warren. “A History of Mechanization in the Cotton South: The Institutional
Hypothesis.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 100 (November 1985): 1191–215.
______. “New Estimates of the Costs of Harvesting Cotton: 1949–1964.” Research in
Economic History 13 (1999): 199–225.
Wilber, Charles K. The Soviet Model and Underdeveloped Countries. Chapel Hill: Univer-
sity of North Carolina Press, 1969.