Wage Differentials and Heterogenous Jobs
Wage Differentials and Heterogenous Jobs
Wage Differentials and Heterogenous Jobs
Compensating differentials
Compensating differentials refers to the extra income given to a worker in exchange for a
negative job attribute that does not exist in alternative jobs. Also known as a salary premium or a
pay equalizer. The pay disparity is due to a decrease in the supply of workers for jobs with
unfavorable job characteristics and an increase in the supply of workers for alternative jobs. No-
wage features of work vary widely and are a source of wage differential compensation. These
compensating differentials are equilibrium wage differentials in that and they do not lead
employees to shift to higher-paying employment, causing wages to equalize.
Sources of wage differentials
• Risk of job injury/death: When there is a high danger of getting hurt or killed on the
job, the labor supply for that occupation will be lower than for jobs with safe working
conditions. Compensation for salary differentials will be paid in employment with a
higher risk of accidents than other occupations.
• Fringe Benefits: Employers who recruit comparable people and pay comparable salary
rates have a wide range of fringe perks. For example, sick leave, paid vacations, and
medical insurance, to name a few. Firms that do not offer fringe benefits will be required
to pay compensatory salary differentials in order to recruit skilled personnel. The gross
hourly compensatory pay differentials between two businesses will be equalized as a
result of this.
• Job status: Some occupations, such as those in the electronics sector, provide significant
status and reputation and attract a huge number of people. Other jobs, such as working in
a sewage treatment facility, have a lower rank and reputation. To recruit workers, this
industry must provide compensatory salary differentials. As a result, job status has an
impact on labor supply, and compensating compensation differentials may arise as a
result.
• Job location: Similar jobs have a wide range of employment locations, which affects the
cost of living. Cities like Islamabad, which are known for their livability, may attract a
big number of employees. Cities with an industrial smoke problem are less appealing to
employees. Faisalabad, for example. As a result, pay differentials may need to be
compensated.
• Job security: Various occupations give long-term job security and guarantee that one
will work a full week every week throughout the year. Other jobs, such as construction
and consulting, have a lot of ups and downs in terms of employment and pay. Because a
consistent wage check is not guaranteed every week of the year. These jobs appeal to a
small number of individuals. Workers in these jobs may be eligible for compensatory
salary differentials. The hourly income may be rather high in order to compensate for the
low likelihood of working 40 hours per week for the full year.
• Prospects of job advancement: In addition, jobs vary in terms of how much a company
invests in human capital over the course of a year. For example, a 22-year-old banking
employee can expect on-the-job training and the possibility of advancement to a higher-
paying position over time. A carpenter's earnings are unlikely to rise much over time.
Analysis
Wage dispersion is one of the most important predictions of Efficiency Wage Models, as
previously stated. However, neither the competitive model nor the majority of Efficiency Wage
Models can explain why companies using various technologies coexist in the same sector. In this
respect, Efficiency Wage Models can only explain the presence of inter-industry pay disparities,
not intra-industry wage disparities. As a result, to induce interindustry dispersion, some external
assumption is required.
To obtain heterogeneity across businesses, one option proposed in the literature is to suppose that
one source of production has a flexible supply to the industry but a constant supply to the
business. Furthermore, we may assume that there are empirical issues that result in intra-industry
heterogeneity, i.e., we will see some product difference even if we are very diligent in our
empirical research of the industry.
Wage premium and company characteristics are also predicted by efficiency wage models, albeit
the relation between the two sets of variables differs depending on the model. In this way,
Efficiency Pay Models formalize prior claims concerning the impact of industry factors on wage
dispersion reported in the literature. Consider Lester's and Stigler's monitoring and screening
hypotheses, respectively. The relationships between Efficiency Wage Models and company
features, as well as the predictions of Efficiency Wage Models in terms of firm wage behavior,
The nutritional model predicts that the efficiency wage for employees in surplus supply will
remain constant, that various pay arrangements will exist for employees on long- and short-term
contracts, and that stable long-term employment arrangements would predominate (Rodgers,
1975 and Bliss, and Stern, 1978).
A recruitment model (Lang, 1988) is an exception, in which a vector of capital and salary
combinations is in equilibrium. 8 Oi (1983) shows that, under the premise that entrepreneurial
talent is a specific scarce input, an industry would contain heterogeneous enterprises of various
sizes and production structures. Higher salaries are predicted under the shirking model in
companies with high monitoring expenses and/or a high cost of employee misbehavior.
Similarly, in organizations where turnover is more costly, the turnover model predicts higher
pay. Various hypotheses then connect these efficiency wage costs to observable business
features.
Large companies are thought to have greater shirking/monitoring expenses. Because bigger
companies' production processes are more intertwined, every breakdown, delay, or industrial
accident will be more expensive. Furthermore, greater wages save monitoring entrepreneurial
time, which has a bigger opportunity cost in bigger corporations.
Furthermore, shirking may be linked to capital endowment, in the sense that it will be costly for
businesses that utilize pricey capital equipment (in the extreme shirking could be associated with
smashing the machines or stealing inputs or products). The size of the company has also been
linked to turnover expenses.
If companies share at least some of these expenses, they will be more motivated to limit
turnover. Large companies also have greater screening expenses. Weiss and Landau (1984)
propose a screening model in which the productivity of a firm's top workers and the quantity of
applications are determined by salaries. They show that salaries and business size are positively
associated in this situation. As result that is driven by the fact that large firms need more
workers.
Large enterprises have a greater cost of getting worker information under Garen's (1985) model.
Because of the disparities in screening processes between large and small businesses, there is a
positive correlation between company size and salaries. The author's estimates seem to support
both hypotheses. A link between capital, profits, and salaries is predicted by the recruitment
models.
Workers are concerned with their wage and opportunity cost in most Efficiency Wage Models,
which are assessed by an average wage and the unemployment rate. Workers are also worried
about their relative pay inside the business and their previous earnings, according to the
sociological model, since these relative salaries impact their view of being treated properly.
Large, capital-intensive companies, in particular, should choose for a system that mitigates the
effects of shirking or allows for easier monitoring. However, based on the aforementioned
reasoning, we conclude that efficiency wage models imply that large enterprises with substantial
capital investments and profitability should anticipate higher pay. Furthermore, the sociological
model predicts that enterprises would pay all jobs high or low wages.
For two different sets of employers and workers, this graph depicts the best combination of wage
rate and job safety. The employees have similar human capital pools, but differ in their
preferences for the nonwage job amenity of safety. Given the condition of competition in
respective industries, the iso-profit curves depict the greatest profit levels feasible for the
enterprises. The slopes of the curves show how much it costs each business to improve worker
safety.
Conclusion
Wage dispersion is one of the most important predictions of Efficiency Wage Models, as
previously stated. In this respect, Efficiency Wage Models can only explain the presence of inter-
industry pay disparities, not intra-industry wage disparities. Wage premium and company
characteristics are also predicted by efficiency wage models, albeit the relation between the two
sets of variables differs depending on the model. In this way, Efficiency Pay Models formalize
prior claims concerning the impact of industry factors on wage dispersion reported in the
literature.
The relationships between Efficiency Wage Models and company features, as well as the
predictions of Efficiency Wage Models in terms of firm wage behavior, Workers are concerned
with their wage and opportunity cost in most Efficiency Wage Models, which are assessed by an
average wage and the unemployment rate.
References
Kyyrä, T. (2007). Retrieved from
https://helda.helsinki.fi/bitstream/handle/10138/21792/studieso.pdf?sequence=1
Maczulskij, T. (2013, june 6). Retrieved from
https://jyx.jyu.fi/bitstream/handle/123456789/41560/1/978-951-39-5215-
0_vaitos06062013.pdf
Romaguera, P. (1991). Retrieved from
https://kellogg.nd.edu/sites/default/files/old_files/documents/153_0.pdf
Sullivan, P. (2013, september). Retrieved from https://www.bls.gov/osmr/research-
papers/2013/pdf/ec130100.pdf